Page images
PDF
EPUB

sharing contracts frequently is necessary. However, where the level of contractor effort desired can be identified and agreed upon in advance of performance, negotiation of a firm fixedprice contract should be considered.

(c) Development and test. Where possible, a final commitment to undertake specific product development and test should be avoided until preliminary exploration and studies have indicated a high degree of probability that the development is feasible and the Government generally has determined both its minimum requirements for product performance and schedule completion and its desired performance and schedule completion objectives. The precision with which the performance objectives can be defined will largely determine the type of contract employed, with firm-fixed-price contracts receiving first consideration. In development programs where use of cost and performance incentives are considered desirable and administratively practicable, fixed-price-incentive and cost-plus-incentive-fee contracts are to be considered in that order of preference. The solicitation should describe the Government's minimum requirements for product performance and schedule completion, its desired performance and schedule completion objectives, and the type of contract contemplated. The Government's minimum requirements for product performance and schedule completion generally should not be considered subject to negotiation. The solicitation should also indicate the factors on which the Government will evaluate proposals and which of those factors the Government considers most important (e.g., greater weight may be assigned to the range of an aircraft than to its speed). When incentive contracts are to be used, contractors shall be required to submit targets and incentive sharing arrangements for meeting or surpassing the Government's requirements for performance and for schedule completion, together with an estimate of the cost thereof. The targets proposed by each offeror, the estimated cost thereof, and the sharing arrangements proposed should, to the extent practical, be con

sidered by the Government in the contractor selection process. When this approach to contractor selection has been used, the resulting development program should be performed under an incentive contract which includes performance, schedule completion, and cost targets, the requisite test procedures by which attainment of performance targets will be measured, and provisions for varying profits to the extent targets are or are not met. In order to provide maximum incentive, the swing of profit variation should in each case be as wide as practical (see § 1-3.405-4(b)). The introduction of incentives into development is of such compelling importance that, to the extent practical, firms not willing to negotiate appropriate incentive provisions may be excluded from consideration for the award of development contracts.

§ 1-3.404 Fixed-price contracts.

§ 1-3.404-1 General.

Fixed-price contracts are of several types so designed as to facilitate proper pricing under varying circumstances. The fixed-price type contracts provide for a firm price, or under appropriate circumstances may provide for an adjustable price, for the supplies or services which are being procured. In providing for an adjustable price, the contract may fix a ceiling price, target price (including target cost), or minimum price. Unless otherwise provided in the contract, any such ceiling, target, or minimum price is subject to adjustment only if required by the operation of any contract clause which provides for equitable adjustment, escalation, or other revision of the contract price upon the occurrence of an event or a contingen

cy.

§ 1-3.404-2 Firm fixed-price contract.

(a) Description. The firm fixed-price contract provides for a price which is not subject to any adjustment by reason of the cost experience of the contractor in the performance of the contract. This type of contract, when appropriately applied as set forth in this § 1-3.404-2, places maximum risk

upon the contractor. Because the contractor assumes full responsibility, in the form of profits or losses, for all costs under or over the firm fixed price, he has a maximum profit incentive for effective cost control and contract performance. Use of the firm fixed-price contract imposes a minimum administrative burden on the contracting parties.

(b) Application. The firm fixed-price contract is suitable for use in procurements when reasonably definite design or performance specifications are available and whenever fair and reasonable prices can be established at the outset, such as where:

(1) Adequate competition has made initial proposals effective;

(2) Prior purchases of the same or similar supplies or services under competitive conditions or supported by valid cost or pricing data provide reasonable price comparisons;

(3) Cost or pricing information is available permitting the development of realistic estimates of the probable costs of performance;

(4) The uncertainties involved in contract performance can be identified and reasonable estimates of their possible impact on costs made, and the contractor is willing to accept a firm fixed price at a level which represents assumption of a reasonable proportion of the risks involved; or

(5) Any other reasonable basis for pricing can be used consistent with the purpose of this type of contract.

The firm fixed-price contract is particularly suitable in the purchase of standard or modified commercial items, or of any other items for which sound prices can be developed.

§ 1-3.404-3 Fixed-price contract with escalation.

(a) Description. The fixed-price contract with escalation provides for the upward and downward revision of the stated contract price upon the occurrence of certain contingencies which are specifically defined in the contract. The risks in a fixed-price contract are reduced by the inclusion of escalation provisions in which the parties agree to revise the stated price upon the happening of a prescribed

is

contingency. Where escalation agreed upon, upward adjustments shall be limited by the establishment of a reasonable ceiling, and provisions will be included for downward adjustments in those instances where the prices or rates fall below the base levels provided in the contract. In the establishment of the base levels fromR which escalation will operate, contingency allowances shall be eliminated from the base to be set forth in the contract to the extent that escalation is provided for any particular contingency. Generally, escalation provisions are of two broad types.

(1) Price escalation provides for adjustment of the contract price on the basis of increases or decreases from an agreed upon level in published or established prices of specific items or in price levels of the contract end items.

(2) Labor and material escalation provides for adjustment of the contract price on the basis of increases or decreases from agreed standards or indices in wage rates, specific materials costs, or both.

(b) Application. Use of this type of contract is appropriate where serious doubt exists as to the stability of market and labor conditions which will exist during an extended period of production and where contingencies which would otherwise be included in a firm fixed-price contract are identifiable and can be covered separately by escalation. Its usefulness is limited by the difficulties inherent in its administration. Escalation should be restricted, to the extent possible, to industrywide contingencies, and labor and material escalation should be limited to contingencies beyond the normal control of the contractor.

§ 1-3.404-4 Fixed-price incentive contract. (a) Description-(1) General. The fixed-price incentive contract is a fixed-price type contract with provision for adjustment of profit and establishment of the final contract price by a formula based on the relationship which final negotiated total cost bears to total target costs.

(2) Firm target. Under the firm target type of incentive contract there is negotiated at the outset a target

com

cost, a target profit, a price ceiling (but not a profit ceiling or floor), and a formula for establishing final profit and price. After performance of the contract, the final cost is negotiated and the final contract price is then established in accordance with the formula. Where the final cost is less than target cost, application of the formula results in a final profit greater than the target profit; conversely, where final cost is more than target cost, application of the formula results in a final profit less than the target profit, or even a net loss. Thus, within the price ceiling, the formula provides for the Government and the contractor to share the responsibility for costs greater or less than those originally estimated, as determined by a parison of negotiated final cost with target cost. Because the profit resulting from application of the formula is in inverse relationship to costs, the formula provides the contractor in advance with a calculable profit incentive to control costs. To provide an incentive consistent with the circumstances, the formula should reflect the relative risks involved in contract performance. Thus, it is appropriate in certain procurements to establish a formula which provides for contractor assumption of a considerable or major share of total cost responsibility. In such circumstances, when a major share of total cost responsibility is assumed by the contractor, every consideration should be given to establishing target profits which reflect assumption of such responsibility.

(3) Successive targets. Under the successive targets type of incentive contract, there is negotiated at the outset an initial target cost, an initial target profit, a price ceiling, a formula for fixing the firm target profit, and a production point at which the formula will be applied. Generally, the production point will be prior to delivery or shop completion of the first item. This formula does not apply for the life of the contract but simply is used to fix the firm target profit for the contract. The initial formula shall also provide for a ceiling and floor on the firm target profit. To provide an incentive consistent with the circumstances, the

formula for fixing the firm target profit should reflect the relative risk involved in establishing an incentive arrangement where cost and pricing information were not sufficient to permit the negotiation of firm targets at the outset (see § 1-3.404-4(b)(3)). Thus it normally will not provide for as great a degree of contractor cost responsibility as would a formula for establishing final profit and price. When the production point for applying the formula is reached, the firm target cost is then negotiated, consideration being given to experienced cost and all other pertinent factors, and the firm target profit is automatically determined in accordar ce with the formula. At this point, two alternatives are possible. First, a firm fixed price may be negotiated using as a guide the firm target cost plus the firm target profit. Second, if use of the firm fixed price is determined to be inappropriate, a formula for establishing final profit and price may be negotiated, using the firm target profit and the firm target cost. As in the firm target type of contract described in § 1-3.404-4(a)(2), the final cost is negotiated at the completion of the contract and the final contract price is then established in accordance with the formula for establishing final profit and price.

(4) Billing price. In either of the types of contract described in (2) and (3) of this § 1-3.404-4(a), a billing price will be established as an interim basis for payment. This billing price may be adjusted within the ceiling limits, upon request of either party to the contract, when it becomes apparent that final negotiated costs will be substantially different from the target cost.

(b) Application. (1) Fixed-price incentive contracts are appropriate when use of the firm fixed-price contract is inappropriate, and the supplies or services being procured are of such a nature that assumption of a degree of cost responsibility by the contractor is likely to provide him with a positive profit incentive for effective cost control and contract performance. It may also be appropriate to negotiate additional incentive provisions covering performance levels and more timely

delivery (see § 1-3.407-2). Contract performance requirements must be such that there is reasonable opportunity for the incentive provisions to have a meaningful impact on the manner in which the contractor manages the work.

(2) The firm target type of incentive contract, described in § 1-3.404-4(a)(2), is appropriate for use whenever a firm target and a formula for establishing final profit and price can be negotiated at the outset which will provide a fair and reasonable incentive.

(3) The successive targets type of incentive contract, described in § 13.404-4(a)(3), is appropriate for use whenever available cost and pricing information is not sufficient to permit the negotiation of realistic firm targets at the outset. However, enough information should be available to permit negotiation of initial targets, and there should be reasonable assurance that additional reliable information will be available at an early point in the performance of the contract so as to permit negotiation of either a firm fixed price, or firm targets and a formula for establishing final profit and price, which will provide a fair and reasonable incentive. The additional information need not in all cases come from experience under the contract itself, but may be drawn from experience on any other contracts for the same or similar items.

(c) Limitations. Fixed-price incentive contracts shall not be used unless the contractor's accounting system is adequate for price revision purposes and permits satisfactory application of the profit and price adjustment formulas. In no case should such contracts be used where (1) cost or pricing information adequate for firm targets is not available at the time of initial contract negotiation or at a very early point in performance, or (2) the sole or principal purpose is to shift substantially all cost responsibility to the Government. In no case shall the firm target profit or the formula for final profit and price be established prior to the negotiation of the firm target cost. Neither type of fixed-price incentive contract shall be used unless a determination has been made, in accord

ance with the requirements of Subpart 1-3.3, that such method of contracting is likely to be less costly than other methods, or that it is impractical to secure supplies or services of the kind or quality required without the use of such type of contract.

§ 1-3.404-5 Prospective price redetermination at a stated time or times during performance.

(a) Description. This type of contract provides for a firm fixed price for an initial period of contract deliveries or performance and for prospective price redetermination either upward or downward at a stated time or times during the performance of the contract. It also may provide for a price ceiling, where appropriate. Once established, ceiling prices are subject to adjustment only by reason of the operation of other contract clauses (see § 1-3.404-1).

(b) Application. This type of contract is appropriate in procurements calling for quantity production or services where it is possible to negotiate fair and reasonable firm fixed prices for an initial period, but not for subsequent periods of contract performance. This initial period should be the longest period for which it is possible to establish fair and reasonable firm fixed prices at the time of original negotiation. The length of the prospective pricing periods should depend on the circumstances of each case and should generally be at least twelve months each. Ceiling prices, where appropriate, should be based on the evaluation of the uncertainties involved in contract performance, and their possible impact on cost, and should be negotiated at a level which represents contractor assumption of a reasonable degree of risk.

(c) Limitations. This type of contract shall not be used unless:

(1) It has been established through negotiations that a firm fixed-price contract does not fulfill the requirements established by the conditions surrounding the procurement;

(2) The contractor's accounting system is adequate for price redetermination purposes;

1

(3) The prospective pricing period can be made to conform with the operation of the contractor's accounting system; and

(4) Reasonable assurance exists that price redetermination action will be taken promptly at the time or times specified.

§ 1-3.404-6 [Reserved]

§ 1-3.404-7 Retroactive price redetermination after completion.

(a) Description. This type of contract provides for a ceiling price and retroactive price redetermination after completion of the contract. The redetermined price should be negotiated so as to give weight to the management effectiveness and ingenuity exhibited by the contractor during performance, and the basis for such negotiation should be fully discussed with the contractor when this type of contract is negotiated. Because the price is redetermined on a completely retroactive basis, this contract type (except for the price ceiling) does not provide the contractor with a calculable incentive for effective cost control. Once established, the ceiling price is subject to adjustment only if required by the operation of other contract clauses (see § 1-3.404-1).

(b) Application. This type of contract is appropriate in procurements where it is established at the time of negotiation that a fair and reasonable firm fixed price cannot be negotiated and the amount involved is so small or the time for performance so short that use of any other type of contract is impracticable. Even in these situations, however, it should be used only after negotiation of a billing price as fair and reasonable as the circumstances of the particular procurement permit. Based on an evaluation of the circumstances involved in contract performance, and their possible impact on cost, the ceiling price should be negotiated at a level which represents contractor assumption of a reasonable degree of risk.

(c) Limitations. This type of contract shall not be used unless the procurement is for research and development at an estimated cost of $100,000 or less, and

[blocks in formation]

(a) Description. The cost-reimbursement type of contract provides for payment to the contractor of allowable costs incurred in the performance of the contract, to the extent prescribed in the contract. This type of contract establishes an estimate of total cost for the purpose of obligation of funds, and a ceiling which the contractor may not exceed (except at his own risk) without prior approval or subsequent ratification of the contracting officer.

(b) Application. The cost-reimbursement type contract is suitable for use only when the uncertainties involved in contract performance are of such magnitude that cost of performance cannot be estimated with sufficient reasonableness to permit use of any type of fixed-price contract. In addition, it is essential that (1) the contractor's cost accounting system is adequate for the determination of costs applicable to the contract, and (2) appropriate surveillance by Government personnel during performance will give reasonable assurance that inefficient or wasteful methods are not being used.

(c) Limitations. The cost-reimbursement type contract may be used only after a determination, in accordance with Subpart 1-3.3, that:

(1) Such method of contracting is likely to be less costly than other methods; or

(2) It is impractical to secure property or services of the kind or quality required without the use of such type of contract.

« PreviousContinue »