Page images
PDF
EPUB

EXHIBIT IX

EXCERPTS FROM COMMITTEE PRINT ENTITLED "THE IMPACT OF THE PATENT SYSTEM ON RESEARCH", ISSUED BY THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON PATENTS, TRADEMARKS, AND COPYRIGHTS, SENATE COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY (STUDY NO. 11), 85TH CONG., 2D SESS.

A study of the Subcommittee on Patents, Trademarks, and Copyrights of the Senate Committee on the Judiciary (Study No. 11), 85th Cong., 2d sess., prepared by Professor Melman)

Modern scientific and engineering research is increasingly characterized by the integrated application of the work of various specialists. The resulting conditions of interdependence in inquiry render the concept of the inventor obsolete to a considerable extent. The functions once embodied in the solo inventors who dominated the technical scene are now more often than not performed by various persons working in a cooperative group effort. To the extent that this is true, the traditional patent system, with its emphasis upon the protection and reward of the inventor, necessarily becomes less attuned to the purpose that it was set up to perform (p. 18).

[blocks in formation]

Scientists and engineers are now largely employees paid to exercise their occupational skills. This pavment is on a time, not a unit of production, basis, and is substantially independent of patent taking. Much of the scientific work is done in nonprofit institutions, and here it is carried on with virtually no accompanying patenting activity (p. 21).

[blocks in formation]

There are no established and accepted ways of evaluating the money worth of patents, either in terms of cost or in terms of market value. The cost aspect is of greatest interest here. The difficulty in evaluating the cost of producing a given patent stems from the character of research. Where the activities of many persons must be integrated as necessary conditions for the production of given knowledge there are no known methods for obtaining an objective measure of the total worth of the inputs required to produce a given result (p. 22).

It is noted that the factors influencing industrial research activity are the changing circumstances of interfirm competition, much more than the availability of patents. Likewise, the conduct of research in universities and other nonbusiness groups is largely independent of patent considerations, since in the nonbusiness laboratories knowledge is produced for its own sake and the search for knowledge irrespective of its commercial and industrial value, is a primary criterion in selecting research projects (p. 26).

a. patent activity and business-sponsored research

Among persons who are active in the patent field, there is substantial agreement that the opportunity to obtain patents has been a potent incentive for research outlays by industrial firms. If this assumption is valid, it supports

the contention that patenting is an important factor in industrial research. But do the facts support the assertion? One way to find out is to examine the relation between patenting and research activities. The relation between research and patent activity can be approached in two ways, to wit, in aggregate terms and through the detailed records of particular firms.

For the period 1941-54 there are reliable estimates of the total number of research scientists and engineers in the United States. These data can be compared with the number of patents granted on inventions by the Patent Office. The data of table 1 show a dramatic growth in the number of scientists and engineers from 87,000 in 1941 to 194,000 in 1954, an increase of 120 percent. During the same period the number of patents issued shows a marked fall. Even if allowance is made for administrative problems of the Patent Office and other factors, the larger picture that emerges is plain enough. There has been no growth in the number of patents taken on inventions that matches

the increased number of scientists and engineers in the industrial and other research laboratories in the country.1

TABLE I.-The number of patents granted for inventions in relation to the growth of research scientists and engineers

[blocks in formation]

Department of Defense, Office of the Secretary of Defense (Research and Development), The Growth of Scientific Research and Development, at 12 (1953). 2 Department of Commerce, Historical Statistics of the United States, 1789-1945, at 312 (1949); Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1954, at 520 (1954); id., 1955, at 505 (1955).

Even more striking is the lag that appears when one examines technological effort generally. Activity in patenting as compared with change in the total number of scientists and engineers, not just those engaged in research and development work, is shown by table 2. As this table shows, from 1900 to 1954 there occurred a massive expansion in the number of scientists and engineers from 42,000 to 691,000, an increase of 1,600 percent. In contrast, over this same period the largest increase shown in any given year in the number of patents granted was only 83 percent over the number granted in 1900 and in most years the increase was even smaller than this. The relationship between the growth of the number of scientists and engineers and the number of patents granted is reflected in the fifth column of table 2, by dividing the index of patent growth by the index showing the growth in scientists and engineers. The data show a steady and persistent decline from 1900 to date in patenting as compared to overall scientific and engineering employment. In other words, activity in taking out patents has lagged increasingly behind the total activity in science and engineering, as indicated in the growth of the total population of scientists and engineers, until today it is less than one tenth of what it would be had it kept pace2 (pp. 27-28). B. Emphasis upon patenting weakens the universities as scientific centers

Insofar as concern with patenting spreads through the universities, they become correspondingly less valuable as producers of new knowledge. This results from: (1) the tendency to select problems for research on the basis of whether they will lead to patentable inventions, not whether they will add to the store of knowledge as an end in itself; (2) the introduction of managerial decision making over investigators; (3) restrictions on publication; and finally, (4) adverse effects on the students themselves. These effects on the characteristics of university-located research are independent of the availability of larger budgets, better buildings, and more staff (p. 40).

[blocks in formation]

1 One may properly ask whether it takes more manpower and costs more to make a given invention today than it used to? The data available here do not give a direct answer to this question. The several tables shown in this chapter do show, however, that the differences in rates of development between technical employment (and budgets) and patenting are large, both in the long run (1900-1954) and during shorter periods (1941-54, 1950-55, 1940-55, and 1942-54). It seems unlikely that changes in the state and circumstances of science and production technology during these shorter periods have been sufficiently great to explain the lag in patenting activity shown by these statistics. The writer is advised that there is no indication of any steady upgrading, over the decades, in the Patent Office standards of invention which would account for the reduction in patenting at least to an extent beyond that which would balance the increased competency of technicians. Whitmore, "What's Got Into the Office Lately?" 29 J.P.O.S. 869 (1947); cf. hearings before the Senate Subcommittee on Patents, Trademarks, and Copyrights, 84th Cong., 1st sess., at 72-95 (Oct. 10-12, 1955).

2 It may be suggested that the growth in Government-contracted research work during recent years may involve the employment of technical men on work that is not conducive to patenting by the contractor firm, since the patents would be Government-owned. This would not, however, explain the decline shown in table 2, which shows relative patenting activity since 1900. Nor does it explain the situation among the individual firms, as shown in tables 3 to 6 and in figure 1. Of the firms, only one is very active in Governmentcontracted research and development, and the data for this firm have been adjusted to exclude the Government-contract research staff.

Pressures for aggressive patenting start in universities in the interest of securing additional funds for research and teaching. However, the managerial characteristics of the directed research efforts that tend to flow from this policy and are undertaken toward this end, abridge the free pursuit of knowledge as an end in itself. In turn, these methods tend to have a weakening effect upon the functioning of universities as centers for scientific work. Thus, in the long run, pressures for patenting and similar efforts, if sustained, could exhaust the resources of the university that are essential for the training of new investigators and the pursuit of knowledge as an end in itself (p. 43).

[blocks in formation]

Patent-oriented control of research, as one aspect of the use of knowledge as property, leads to effects that run contrary to the requirements of efficient promotion of science. Business criteria, like any other closely defined criteria for selection of research problems, restrict the scope of acceptable problems and the freedom of the investigator. Business requirements for keeping knowledge secret block the free publication that is a necessary part of the process of inquiry.

The effects noted here are especially important in the promotion of science because of the interdependence and need for integration of knowledge which was described in chapter III, above. Under such conditions, the people who decide on research projects, the criteria used, and policies on publication affect the degree to which scientist and engineers may participate in the necessarily integrated effort of the expansion of technical knowledge. Insofar as the pursuit of patent rights contributes to research and publication policies that contradict the requirements of interdependence and integration, it may be said that the direction of effects of a patent system contradicts the requirements for the progress of science and technology (p. 48).

There is nothing to indicate that the absence of the patent system would diminish the scope or character of scientific research in the universities. Indeed, insofar as patent pressures were removed from university scientists, this would probably strengthen the universities as producers of science and technology. Moreover, business expenditures for research, in the estimate of this writer, would not be appreciably diminished by the elimination of opportunities for claiming patent rights. It is true that in the absence of patenting, some of the characteristics of industrial research might be revised. Competitive pressures along product and production cost lines, that now impel the expansion of industrial research outlays would, however, continue to be operative (p. 56).

*

The evidence and analyses of this study indicate that there is a growing disharmony between the efficient production of new technical knowledge and the effort, through the patent system, to treat that knowledge under property relations. This disharmony is intensified as the division of labor in science increases and, as a consequence, the conduct of inquiry becomes increasingly social production that requires the integration of interdependent technical skills. These developments make it increasingly difficult to specify what is new, what is invention, and who is an inventor. The effects from these factors would not be essentially altered, in this writer's opinion, by variation in the rules for establishing property rights to knowledge.

The effort to operate a patent system formulated for the technological conditions of a century ago has proved to be increasingly awkward. The problems of patent-system operation, however, do not stem primarily from administrative shortcomings or from the absence of ingenuity among the able attorneys, judges, and Patent Office staffs who administer the system. Rather, they stem from the inability to apply the conceptions of a bygone era to the contemporary conditions under which technical knowledge is produced. At the same time, there can be little doubt that the patent system has been a useful instrument in industrial management's competitive process.

In this investigation, attention has been focused on the problem: Does the patent system now fulfill the constitutional purpose of promoting science and the useful arts, as indicated by the operation of industrial and nonprofit research laboratories? On balance, based upon the study of selected typical industrial and nonprofit research laboratories, the answer is "No."

The patent system in the contemporary scene has not, as a rule, promoted conditions that facilitate research in science or the industrial arts. On the contrary: In universities the effect of patenting pressures has been to inter49646-6016

pose managerial controls and commercial pressures where free, uninhibited inquiry is needed to promote the flow of science. In industrial laboratories research in the useful arts has been expanded rapidly, without a parallel growth in patenting activity. Moreover, the experience of a few firms, whose patent privileges have been recently abridged, indicates that these managements maintain and expand their industrial research in order to cope with problems of product and cost competition. The development of research in these and similar firms will bear close watching.

With or without a patent system, the efficient pursuit of knowledge in the universities and other nonprofit institutions will continue, within the limits of available resources, so long as the production of knowledge is treated as a sufficient end in itself. Industrial firms will continue to enlarge their research in the useful arts as dictated by competitive needs, with or without patent privileges. Henceforth, in the judgment of this writer, the main impetus for the promotion of science and the useful arts will come, not from the patent system, but from forces and factors that lie outside that system (pp. 61-62).

*

Senator LONG. We will now proceed and hear Mr. Anderson.

STATEMENT OF ROLAND A. ANDERSON, ASSISTANT GENERAL
COUNSEL FOR PATENTS, ATOMIC ENERGY COMMISSION; ACCOM-
PANIED BY PHILIP G. READ, SMALL BUSINESS SPECIALIST, AEC
Mr. ANDERSON. I believe the committee has the prepared statement.
If you would like me to skip over and merely hit some of the high-
lights I would be pleased to do so at the committee's request.
Senator LONG. You may proceed as you wish."**

Mr. ANDERSON. Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, it is a pleasure to present the present policies and practices of the United States Atomic Energy Commission.

THE COMMISSION CONTRACT POLICY

The Commission has pursued a policy in its funded research and development and operating contracts of employing patent provisions under which the Commission is in position to acquire all rights in inventions and discoveries in the atomic energy field. This policy was initially promulgated by the Commission's predecessor, the Mahattan Engineering District, and is in general, similar to the usual commercial and industrial practice where the private sponsoring company generally acquires all rights in inventions and discoveries that result from the privately sponsored and funded research and development work.

It is the Commission's view that where the Commission sponsors and pays for research and development in the field of atomic energy that the resultant inventions and discoveries should be the property of the Government for the benefit, not only of the particular contractor, but of the general public. This policy of the acquisition of all rights in inventions and discoveries in the atomic energy field together with a corollary technical data provision under which the Commission acquires rights in the data to use the same as it sees fit, has permitted the Commission and the Government generally, complete freedom of action as respects the dissemination of scientific and technological atomic energy information prepared and developed 23a Mr. Anderson read his complete statement.

under Commission contracts to the entire public, in the public interest and not just to contractors and other selected groups. The Commission's ownership of the rights in the discoveries and inventions in the atomic energy field has avoided the granting of special privileges and the establishment of preferred positions by contractors. While the AEC has a substantial number of research and development prime and subcontracts, as noted in the list of research and development prime and subcontracts reported during the 5-year period 1954-58, as set forth in appendix A,236 yet much of the programmatic research and development is performed by relatively few contractors. To the end of 1958 approximately 90 percent of the inventions reported under Commission contracts have been reported by some 14 Commission contractors, so that, if AEC had a policy of acquiring only a governmental license, the possibility of establishing preferred positions does exist.

One of the present effects of the AEC patent and technical data policy is that all unclassified technological and scientific information prepared and developed by the Commission and its contractors is presently available to every company presently engaged in atomic energy work. Everyone is entitled to use the scientific and technical data and the inventions and discoveries that have resulted from Commission contracts. This utilization of technology would not be possible under a program that provided only for royalty-free use by the Government.

This policy, although adopted during the early days of the MED project, has been implemented by the statutory provisions of the Atomic Energy Act of 1954. The 1954 act has three sections dealing specifically with the rights of the Commission in inventions and discoveries resulting from or arising out of Commission contracts— namely sections 152, 159, and 161 (g).

The specific patent article used by the Commission reserves to the Commission the right to determine the disposition of title to and rights in and to any inventions or discoveries made or conceived in the course of, in connection with, or under the terms of the contract. In instances where the contractor has an established industrial and patent position in the nonnuclear field and the research is conducted in other than a Commission laboratory or facility, the article employed provides for the contractor's retention of at least a nonexclusive license. If, in addition thereto the research and development work relates only incidentally to basic research of the Commission and results from more or less routine development work, the contract provision used provides for the retention of a sole license (except as against the Government) in the contractor for purposes other than for use in the production or utilization of special nuclear material or atomic energy. Where the Commission supports research in a field where the contractor has already done some research, which is generally described as a "background position," the Commission also acquires a nonexclusive license for governmental purposes or some other limited purpose in such background contributions. The scope of the background provision is dependent upon the facts of the situation and the particular purposes of the research and development work.

23b See exhibit X(A), p. 238.

« PreviousContinue »